Saturday, March 19, 2011

Monetary policy update and overall outlook summary


The point of this chart is to put into proper perspective the Fed's efforts to inject dollar liquidity into the global economy. It uses a semi-log scale because the change in the amount of bank reserves has been extremely large in the past two years or so. The first stage of Quantitative Easing saw bank reserves soar from about $100 billion to almost $1.3 trillion, and the Fed accomplished this by purchasing MBS and Treasury securities by the bushel, in addition to extending credit to the financial system through swaps, repos and special loans. As the latter injections began unwind, bank reserves shrunk from a high of $1.28 billion in Feb. '10, to $1.07 trillion in Oct. '10. Concerned that they might inadvertently be allowing a tightening of monetary policy at a time when deflation concerns were (allegedly) meaningful and the economy was (allegedly) still struggling, the Fed launched QE2 in Nov. '10. Those purchases have now pushed reserves up to a new high of $1.42 trillion.

Since Oct. '10, bank reserves have increased by $350 billion as a direct result of the Fed's purchases of Treasury securities. But since there has been no unusual growth in the other components of the money supply (e.g., currency and M2), and no huge increase in required reserves (reserves that need to be held against bank deposits) we can conclude that almost all of the increase in bank reserves has served merely to satisfy the economy's and the financial system's demand for bank reserves. And as I've explained before, since bank reserves are essentially obligations of the U.S. government and pay an interest rate similar to that of T-bills, which are considered to be the safest way to hold money in the world, the world was apparently eager to increase its holdings of safe money by $350 billion in recent months, and the Fed was happy to oblige.

If the world (and the banks) had been unwilling to accumulate additional stores of safe money that yields almost nothing, then we would have seen a significant increase in required reserves, a corresponding decrease in excess reserves, and a big increase in the growth of money (currency and M2). Instead of holding excess reserves in growing quantities, banks would have been putting those reserves to work by using them to generate new loans, increased deposits, and more currency. Loans would have generated a yield significantly higher than the yield on bank reserves—a virtual money-making machine. But this is not happening, because banks are satisfied with holding onto more safe, low-yielding cash, and the world in aggregate is apparently unwilling to increase its leverage. M2 is growing at close to a 6% annualized rate, and this is the rate of growth that has prevailed for the past 15 years on average, as the next chart shows. Currency in circulation is up about 7% in the past year, and has only risen at a 5.4% annualized rate in the past two years; again, no sign of any unusual expansion.


In short, the Fed has dumped a ton of reserves into the banking system, but banks have been either unwilling to make new loans, or the economy has no desire to take on more debt, or both. There is still a great deal of uncertainty out there that would explain why reserves have been hoarded instead of utilized: e.g., huge fiscal deficits that raise the specter of huge increases in future tax and regulator burdens, and of course the Fed's own potentially inflationary monetary policy.

The result of all this is that to date the Fed's actions have not been overtly inflationary (i.e., there is no sign that the amount of money in the economy has increased by enough to provoke a significant rise in inflation). However, there are several sensitive and leading indicators that suggest the Fed is in fact making an inflationary mistake: e.g., rising gold and commodity prices, the very weak dollar, and the very steep yield curve. At the same time, there have been numerous signs in the data in the past few months that strongly suggest the economy is picking up speed: e.g., the ISM surveys, rising commodity prices, manufacturing production, car sales, and the decline in unemployment claims. In addition, measures of confidence are starting to perk up, and C&I Loans are picking up, which further suggests that the economy's demand for money is beginning to decline (which would allow 6% money growth to fuel much higher growth in nominal GDP). The biggest positive on the horizon is the likelihood that Congress will finally begin to tackle our out-of-control fiscal policy trainwreck-in-the-making without raising taxes.

I think there is enough smoke out there to be worried about an inflationary fire, but I don't yet see a reason to call for a calamity in the making, as some are (e.g., a dollar collapse, hyperinflation, and another recession/depression). I do think that the risk of deflation is now virtually nil, and that therefore Treasury yields are exceptionally low and at risk of rising significantly. Measures of credit risk are still priced to higher-than-normal default risk, which is unlikely to prevail if money is indeed easy and the price level is set to rise meaningfully. Equity markets are priced with a good deal of fear built in (the Vix is still substantially above its long-term average), PE ratios are about average despite NIPA earnings being at record highs, and earnings yields are higher than corporate bond yields. So I think it still pays to be bullish on the economy, the equity markets, and corporate bonds, but bearish on Treasuries and cash.

10 comments:

  1. Scott,

    Do you think the Japan disaster and unrest in the Middle East will push the world into recession?

    ReplyDelete
  2. Excellent wrap-up by Scott Grannis.

    If I thought the Fed was aggressive before--and I did not--I would recalibrate my thinking now. The Libya-Japan crises suggest QE2 be maintained, and even expanded.

    Now is not the time to fight inflation. Japan has been fighting inflation for 20 years--very successfully. The only problem is that asset values fell 80 percent in that period and wages fell too.

    The USA prospered through Reagan, Bush Sr. and Clinton, all the while inflation ranged in the 2 percent to 4 percent range.

    Since we have been below target for a while, a surge up in the 4 percent range would not be worrisome.

    Also, commodities surge on global demand, and higher commodities prices are needed to bring on more supplies.

    I suggest oil cannot be maintained above $100--too much conservation, substitution and new supply will drive prices down. To put a monetary noose around our necks due to a temporary surge in oil prices is a bad policy.

    Bernanke should print a lot more money.

    ReplyDelete
  3. BTW, an excellent Ramesh Ponnuru piece on the crash of 2008 is up on the National Review website. I

    Ramesh Ponnuru relies heavily on the views of quasi-monetarists like David Beckworth, Josh Hendrickson and Scott Sumner.

    I dearly hope the right-wing takes seriously this new thinking about QE, from a right-wing source. Somehow the right-wing has knee-jerked itself into a rigid position that monetarism means suffocating the economy until it collapses, or protecting bondholders at all costs.

    ReplyDelete
  4. Nice to see your back. Love your site and commentary. You are a very clever dude indeed and I enjoy your timely comments. You are definatly underpaid. Keep up the great work.

    ReplyDelete
  5. Bill: No, I don't think Japan and the Middle East will push the world into recession. Lots of reasons why: The forces of recovery are well in place. The world has had plenty of time to adjust to the problems which led to the last recession. Companies are more profitable and workers are more productive. Monetary policy is many years away from posing a threat to growth. Fiscal policy is going to become more supportive of growth as spending is cut back (stimulus spending never helped the economy to begin with, it only retarded the recovery). The world is full of countries that have a strong growth impulse (e.g. China and India and most emerging market economies). Global trade is largely free and open and that provides a strong impulse to growth for all countries. Neither the Japanese nor the Middle Eastern countries are going to completely shut down; they can't even come close to shutting down, so the world is never going to be missing very much production.

    ReplyDelete
  6. Scott, to your point above, I agree that recovery in the US is well underway, at least in the private sector -- the bigger question looming is how to handle the impending public sector default on bonds and entitlements (which will occur one way or another, either through austerity, inflation, or outright default) -- my gut is telling me that a public sector default is already built into current market prices -- what do you think...?

    I remain committed to and advise everyone to move aggressively into dividend and rent paying equities before matters in the public sector get out of hand...

    ReplyDelete
  7. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  8. PS: The US has been enduring a century of inflation mostly at the hands of long-term fiscal and monetary policies that are consistently inflationary -- I doubt that society has the will or even the power to reverse that apparent feature of modern democracy -- more at:

    http://wjmc.blogspot.com/2011/03/century-of-inflation.html

    Thank you for the opportunity to comment...

    ReplyDelete
  9. as usual, great analysis scott.

    i was with you up to the point in the analysis when it might be interesting to consider the effect of the fed's reversing qe and decreasing the size of its b/s...assuming it ever decides to.

    don't you see long rates going up significantly once the fed is a net seller of treasuries?

    ReplyDelete
  10. I do think long rates will rise significantly, and that will probably happen as signs of inflation increase and the Fed starts tightening. But the rise in rates won't be caused by Fed bond sales, just as its bond purchases haven't caused bond yields to fall. The rise in rates will be driven by an increased inflation premium and by expectations of much higher short-term rates to come.

    ReplyDelete